- Definition: The natural rate of unemployment is the rate of unemployment when the labour market is in equilibrium. It is unemployment caused by structural (supply-side) factors. (e.g. mismatched skills)
Diagram showing the natural rate of unemployment
- The natural rate of unemployment is the difference between those who would like a job at the current wage rate – and those who are willing and able to take a job. In the above diagram, it is the level (Q2-Q1)
- The natural rate of unemployment will therefore include:
- Frictional unemployment
- Structural unemployment. For example, a worker who is not able to get a job because he doesn’t have the right skills
- The natural rate of unemployment is unemployment caused by supply-side factors rather than demand side factors
What Determines the Natural Rate of Unemployment?
Milton Freidman argued the natural rate of unemployment would be determined by institutional factors such as.
- Availability of job information. A factor in determining frictional unemployment and how quickly the unemployed find a job.
- The level of benefits. Generous benefits may discourage workers from taking jobs at the existing wage rate.
- Skills and education. The quality of education and retraining schemes will influence the level of occupational mobilities.
- The degree of labour mobility. See: labour mobility
- Flexibility of the labour market E.g. powerful trades unions may be able to restrict the supply of labour to certain labour markets
- Hysteresis. A rise in unemployment caused by a recession may cause the natural rate of unemployment to increase. This is because when workers are unemployed for a time period they become deskilled and demotivated and are less able to get new jobs.
Explaining Changing Natural Rates of Unemployment
In the post-war period, structural unemployment was very low. During the 1980s, the natural rate of unemployment rose, due to rapid deindustrialisation and a rise in geographical and structural unemployment.
Since 2005, the natural rate of unemployment has fallen.
- Increased labour market flexibility, e.g. trade unions less powerful.
- Privatisation has helped increased competitiveness of industry, leading to more flexible labour markets.
- Rise in self-employment and gig economy, have created new types of jobs.
- Increased monopsony power of employers, who have kept wage growth low, enabling firms to employ more workers.
- Harder to claim unemployment benefits.
Natural Rate of Unemployment in EU
Even during the period of economic growth 2000-2007, unemployment in Eurozone is higher than US and UK. This suggests the Eurozone has a higher natural rate of unemployment.
- Rigidity in EU labour markets e.g. minimum wages and the maximum working week
- Restrictions on closing factories and mandatory severance pay for workers made unemployed, and this makes firms more reluctant to set up in these countries.
- Higher degrees of unionisation resulting in wage rigidity.
- Generous benefits which lessen the pain of unemployment.
- Hysteresis effects. The cyclical recessions of the 1970s and 1980s had long-lasting effects resulting in more unemployment. However, this does not appear to have affected the UK
- Growing competition from Asian countries, lead to structural unemployment from increased job competition.
During 2012-14, the higher unemployment was partly due to lower rates of economic growth – caused by austerity, and deflationary pressures of the Eurozone single currency.
Reducing the natural rate of unemployment
To reduce the natural rate of unemployment, we need to implement supply-side policies, such as:
- Better education and training to reduce occupational immobilities.
- Making it easier for workers and firms to relocated, e.g. more flexible housing market and greater supply in areas of high job demand.
- Making labour markets more flexible, e.g. reducing minimum wages and trade unions.
- Easier to hire and fire workers.
NAIRU and Non-Accelerating Rate of Unemployment
- A very similar concept to the natural rate of unemployment is the NAIRU – the non-accelerating rate of unemployment.
- This is the rate of unemployment consistent with a stable rate of inflation. If you try to reduce unemployment by increasing aggregate demand, then you will get a higher rate of inflation, and the fall in unemployment will prove temporary.
NAIRU explained
- If there is an increase in AD, firms pay higher wages to workers in order to increase in output, this increase in nominal wages encourage workers to supply more labour and therefore unemployment falls.
- However, the increase in AD also causes inflation to increase and therefore real wages do not actually increased but remain the same. Later workers realise that the increase in wages was only nominal and not a real increase.
- Therefore they no longer work overtime. Therefore the supply of labour falls, and unemployment returns to its original or Natural rate of unemployment. It is only possible to reduce unemployment by causing an increase in the rate of inflation. Therefore the natural rate is also known as the NAIRU (non accelerating rate of unemployment.
- This model assumes workers do not correctly predict the rate of inflation but have adaptive expectations.
- Some economists argue workers will correctly predict higher AD causes higher inflation and therefore there will not be even a short term fall in unemployment; this is known as rational expectations.
Example of NAIRU
- In the above example, the natural rate of unemployment is 6%. If you try to reduce unemployment through increased demand, we get a temporary fall in unemployment, but higher inflation. (point A)
- However, this fall in unemployment is unsustainable and the short-run Phillips Curve shifts to SRPC2, and we move to (point C) and unemployment of 6%.
Related